google.com, pub-6007374308804254, DIRECT, f08c47fec0942fa0
More

    Work requirements for Medicaid do not address the real barriers to work and risk throwing many into health insecurity


    Last week in a confirmation hearing, Russel Vought, President Trump’s nominee to run the Office of Management and Budget, said he would support work requirements for Medicaid, the government health insurance program for low-income people. His position—which has also shown up in Republican proposals for the House reconciliation package—was couched in language to “encourage people to get back into the work force, increase labor force participation and give people again the dignity of work.”

    In reality, work requirements have nothing to do with getting people into the workforce. While increasing labor force participation and helping people obtain the dignity of work are important goals, people don’t actually need encouragement to do this. The incentive to work is already there: It gives people sufficient income to not live in grinding poverty. People with income low enough to qualify for social safety net benefits need support from policymakers to access programs like Medicaid and SNAP, not new rounds of bureaucratic paper pushing, which is what work requirements mainly achieve.

    In a new report, I reviewed the research on work requirements and found that almost none of the alleged employment benefits of ratcheting up work requirements are economically significant. Several studies (here, here, and here) have causally estimated the impact of work requirements on SNAP, the food stamp program for low-income adults, and found no increase in employment following more stringent work requirements policies. With respect to Medicaid, two phone surveys in Arkansas following the 2017 introduction of work requirements found no discernible change in employment. This was in part because an estimated 38%–48% of recipients newly subject to work requirements were already working at the 20 hours per week threshold.

    If Mr. Vought was more serious about improving access to work, he would be clear-eyed about the core barriers to work that low-income workers have traditionally faced: weak macroeconomic conditions, the volatile nature of low-wage work, and other barriers to work like caregiving responsibilities.

    With respect to macroeconomic conditions, while today’s labor market is extremely strong, this has not been the norm nor is it something we can assume will persist in the future. The United States has spent far too much time with excess unemployment rates in recent decades. This macroeconomic failure is the responsibility of policymakers—individual workers have little control over the macroeconomic situation, yet it determines whether they are able to find regular work at sustaining wages. Employment rates for low-income adults are highly cyclical, rising when the macroeconomic environment is more favorable and overall unemployment rates fall, and falling when overall unemployment rises due to slack job markets. This is a key signal that these workers mostly do not need “encouragement” or “incentives” to work—they need opportunities. When opportunities arise in the form of strong labor markets, these workers flock to them.

    In my analysis, I explored the association between number of hours worked for low-income adults and the unemployment rate between 1979 and 2019 to see how excess unemployment was related to work time. Figure A shows that as unemployment increases, the number of available jobs in a given local labor market becomes scarce and workers work fewer hours, suggesting that the jobs low-income adults take are much more tied to aggregate labor market health than to work requirements.

    Higher unemployment is associated with fewer work hours for low-income adults: Total hours worked and unemployment rate for the bottom 30% of households, 1979–2019

    year Unemployment rate (%) Hours worked 
    1979 4.95 1235.1
    1980 6.29 1213.1
    1981 6.84 1193.7
    1982 8.98 1150.7
    1983 8.92 1167.3
    1984 6.86 1229.6
    1985 6.61 1266.9
    1986 6.45 1285.2
    1987 5.69 1308.5
    1988 5.03 1320.2
    1989 4.88 1365.5
    1990 5.22 1361.2
    1991 6.46 1334.1
    1992 7.20 1328.4
    1993 6.65 1352.2
    1994 5.89 1361.0
    1995 5.43 1374.9
    1996 5.27 1375.0
    1997 4.82 1382.2
    1998 4.46 1400.1
    1999 4.20 1409.0
    2000 4.04 1400.6
    2001 4.78 1356.1
    2002 5.93 1322.7
    2003 6.17 1307.4
    2004 5.71 1311.8
    2005 5.35 1317.9
    2006 4.90 1349.3
    2007 4.94 1339.4
    2008 6.18 1277.9
    2009 9.72 1177.1
    2010 10.07 1144.2
    2011 9.41 1147.4
    2012 8.65 1173.2
    2013 7.99 1199.0
    2014 6.84 1215.9
    2015 5.98 1255.2
    2016 5.62 1279.4
    2017 5.16 1289.9
    2018 4.71 1319.2
    2019 4.55 1361.0
    ChartData Download data

    The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

    Please enter your comment!
    Please enter your name here

    Stay on op - Ge the daily news in your inbox

    google.com, pub-6007374308804254, DIRECT, f08c47fec0942fa0
    google.com, pub-6007374308804254, DIRECT, f08c47fec0942fa0