google.com, pub-6007374308804254, DIRECT, f08c47fec0942fa0
More

    The Accounting Illusion that Is the U.S. ‘Trade Deficit’


    Trade deficits arise whenever the amount of goods and services that a country imports during some period – say, one month – exceeds the amount of goods and services that it exports during that period. This fact is popularly taken to mean that trade-deficit countries consume more than they produce, with the excess consumption paid for with funds borrowed from abroad or with assets sold to foreigners. If this were true, ongoing trade deficits would impoverish any country that chronically runs them and be unsustainable. But history casts doubt on this common understanding of trade deficits: Despite the US running annual trade deficits every year starting in 1976 (the year I graduated from high school), the real net worth of American households is today (even though I’m now past the official age of retirement) at an all-time high,* as are real per-capita GDP, America’s industrial capacity, and America’s capital stock.

    How is it possible that, in the face of nearly a half-century of uninterrupted annual trade deficits, Americans have gotten richer and our economy stronger?

    Since Adam Smith, economists have repeatedly exposed the many conceptual flaws that infect popular discussions of the balance of trade. Perhaps most significant is the failure to realize that trade deficits are matched by capital inflows – or, as they’re called, “capital-account surpluses.” If, as is true for the US, the bulk of these inflows finance investment rather than consumption, the country’s capital stock grows, thus raising workers’ productivity and citizens’ prosperity. To bemoan rising US trade deficits is to bemoan foreigners’ eagerness to invest in America and the resulting growth of our capital stock and productivity.

    But there’s another way to see why America’s prosperity has increased despite her long-running trade deficits: Large portions of these deficits are the result of a mere accounting convention – specifically, the convention of classifying international cash holdings as investments rather than as imports of the countries in which these holdings increase. This convention masks an important economic reality.

    When foreigners hold US dollars, those dollars are not used to buy American exports. As a result, the US trade deficit grows by the size of these dollar holdings. In balance-of-payments accounting, these dollar holdings are classified as foreign investments in America – technically, as foreigners obtaining American assets. This classification is reasonable, as foreign holders of dollars might anticipate that the dollar’s value will rise against that of other currencies.

    Yet it would be equally reasonable to classify these dollar holdings as American exports. Foreigners supply to America large amounts of textiles, steel, and other goods and services that they produce at a comparative advantage in exchange for a service that America produces at a comparative advantage – namely, the services of a relatively stable and especially useful currency.

    Services supplied by a reliable currency differ in no essential respects from other valuable services that are classified as imports when purchased from abroad (or as exports when sold abroad) – services such as tourism, education, medical care, and investment advice. Because the US economy is so large and prosperous and has sophisticated financial markets – and because the Fed is relatively responsible compared to most other central banks – US dollar holdings provide foreigners with reliable purchasing power that is unique in its worldwide appeal. There are good reasons why the US dollar is the dominant global reserve currency, accounting for 53 percent of official foreign-exchange reserves.

    Therefore, dollars for holding and using abroad are a major American output that we produce and export to foreigners in exchange for goods and services that we import. We should be no less pleased to have a comparative advantage at producing a currency that’s especially useful for global commerce than we are to have a comparative advantage at producing chemicals, IT, or any other good or service. Although in balance-of-payments accounting dollar holdings aren’t treated as an American export, there’s no economic reason why they shouldn’t be. If they were, the measured US trade deficit would be much smaller.





    Source link

    Recent Articles

    5 things to look for in a Christian Financial Class

    The Bible has a lot more to say about money than we think… and so going through a Christian Financial Curriculum makes a...

    Off a Cliff | Econbrowser

    NBER Business Cycle Dating Committee key indicators. Consumption (preliminary) falls markedly. Figure 1: Nonfarm Payroll incl benchmark revision employment from CES (bold blue), implied NFP...

    What Is an Escalation Clause?

    In today’s competitive real estate market, multiple-offer scenarios are becoming increasingly common. Buyers need strategies to stand out without overpaying, and one tool...

    Bessent says housing will ‘unfreeze’ in weeks, sees 2% inflation

    Treasury Secretary Scott Bessent said he expects the U.S. housing market to pick up steam after recent indicators came in below forecasts, and...

    Third-Party Risk Involved in 31% of Cyber Claims

    More merger-and-acquisition activity and technology consolidation have given cyber hackers plenty of entry points to...

    Related Stories

    Leave A Reply

    Please enter your comment!
    Please enter your name here

    Stay on op - Ge the daily news in your inbox

    google.com, pub-6007374308804254, DIRECT, f08c47fec0942fa0
    google.com, pub-6007374308804254, DIRECT, f08c47fec0942fa0